‘UK Air Passenger Demand and CO2 Forecasts’ from the DfT
22.11.2007 Department for Transport
http://www.dft.gov.uk/pgr/aviation/environmentalissues/ukairdemandandco2forecasts/
The Department for Transport produced a report entitled ‘UK Air Passenger Demand
and CO2 Forecasts’ on 22nd November. The 2006 progress report on the 2003 Aviation
White Paper required that the government produce updates in 2007, on the latest
passenger demand, CO2 forecasting, and appraisal methods, as well as updates on
the economic appraisal results.
The numbers of passengers predicted for each UK airport are given on pages 107-8.
This gives low, central and high estimates for the years 2005 (actual CAA figures),
2015 and 2030.
(Jan 2008):
forecasts for passenger demand in Nov 2007 ( ‘
The forecasts
the carbon dioxide forecasts published in 2004. With minor changes, these earlier forecasts formed the basis of the White Paper
on aviation released in Dec 2003, forecasting up to 2030, with an extension to
2050 using a simple methodology.
resulting forecasts are:
Year | Passengers (millions) |
2005 | 228 |
2010 | 270 |
2015 | 325 |
2020 | 375 |
2025 | 430 |
2030 | 480 |
2040 | c540 |
2050 | c580 |
These are ‘constrained’ forecasts, which allow for the fact that some demand
would be suppressed due to anticipated lack of capacity. However, the ‘unconstrained’
demand in 2030 is 495m, just 3% higher. For all practical purposes, therefore,
a ‘predict and provide’ approach for aviation at national level is implied.
These figures are the government’s best estimate or ‘central’ case. A series
of sensitivity tests were performed in which a wide range of parameters were varied
to give a ‘low’ and ‘high’ forecasts. At 2030, the low forecast is 450 (ie 6%
lower than 480) and the high forecast is 505 (ie 5% higher).
AEF comments on the forecasts
the general approach to be reasonable. The underlying assumptions, namely that
demand is basically a function of the growth of the economy and the change in
prices of flying, seem sound and have been used by other forecasters.
of the literature, reported in the paper, and we do not have evidence to confirm
or dispute the results. However, the change of price elasticity since the previous
forecasts from about -1 to -0.44 must engender some suspicion. The use of -1
in the NGOs request for the DfT to rerun ‘SPASM [SPASM is the DfT’s passenger allocation model] with increased prices to reflect a tax on aircraft equal to the tax on petrol,
showed that the demand for air travel would be reduced greatly and the runways
proposed in the White Paper would be unnecessary.
price would have little effect on demand, thereby showing the expansion policy
was robust. The reduction of price elasticity to -0.44 makes the forecast more
robust in this respect. (However, the figure masks big differences: the elasticity
for business travel is thought to be close to zero; for short-haul leisure it
may be around -1.)
to fall from around $100 per barrel, the price at the time of writing, to about
$65 per barrel in 2006 to $53 per barrel in 2030, with most of the decline occurring
by 2012. Given the soaring demand from India and China, and generally uncertainty
about supply (eg ‘peak oil), the assumptions seem totally unrealistic.
This cost is intended to reflect the cost of damage due to global warming and
the forecasts use £70 per tonne (at 2000). AEF has severe misgivings about this
figure. The Stern report gave a range of figures, and there are strong grounds
for supporting a cost as high as £280 per tonne. The use of £70 appears conservative
and helps to boost the net economic benefits of airport expansion.
pollution, are factored into the forecasts. This, together with the low climate
costs means that the price of flying is artificially low, given the stated objective
of getting airlines to meet their full social and environmental cost. Hence, the
demand is much higher than it would be if these costs were included.
placed on air travel because of climate change or for other environmental and
social reasons (other than minimal constraints imposed by airport capacity).
– on either side of the central forecast. Given the intrinsic uncertainties in
forecasting and the long time period involved, this band is patently too narrow.
One reason is that the high and low forecasts do not allow for more than one significant
parameter to vary simultaneously (e.g. lower economic growth combined with a higher
oil prices). The narrow band gives a misleading impression of the robustness of
the forecasts.
is forecast to slow: " .. capacity constraints begin to bite again, so that growth in passenger demand
slows." It appears the government is hypothesising that its ‘predict and provide’
policies, confirmed in the 2003 White Paper, will be continued for many years
and then abandoned. No justification is given for this startling policy about-face.
It is probably no co-incidence that long-term climate targets are set for 2050
but the aviation policies only extend to 2030.